[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
'Dirty Dozen'--Brooke Case -Reply
In response to Charles Mueller's comments (set forth at the
end of my message) on the Supreme Court's position on
interbrand vs. intraband competition:
One argument I've heard (not necessarily my own) in support
of keeping antitrust enforcement out of intrabrand
competition (at least as long as the brand does not have
monopoly power), and one to which I invite responses:
If a manufacturer has independent distributors it has
decided it is more efficient to distribute by contract rather
than vertical integration, because the manufacturer always
has the right to distribute the goods (and set retail prices)
itself. Interference with its decision to contract for
distribution will raise the costs of contract distribution and
encourage the manufacturer to distribute the product itself,
thereby raising the cost of distribution. And the
manufacturer, if it faces competition from other brands, has
incentive to maintain among its dealers the most competitive
price/quality of service to ensure it doesn't lose sales to its
competitors. So, the argument goes, why not just let the
manufacturer worry about whether its distributors compete
among each other, at least if the manufacturer faces
interbrand competition? No distributor could, in any event,
raise the market price above the price the manufacturer
could charge if it handled its own distribution. Thus,
regulating intrabrand competition can increase the cost of
distribution, and restriction of competition among dealers
cannot increase the price the manufacturer would be able to
charge if it were to distribute the product itself.
--John Jacobs
>>> cmueller <cmueller@metrolink.net> 08/02/97
03:05pm >>>
Perhaps I can add some information on the
Liggett/Brookes case, the
Supreme Court's most recent decision on predatory pricing
to concentrate
industries and raise prices. My journal began reporting on it
nearly a
decade ago, when it was in the trial stage, beginning with the
testimony of
the two opposing economic experts, Professors Kenneth
Elzinga (for the
defendants) and William Burnett (plaintiffs). Several
hundred pages of
their testimony, along with jury instructions, briefs, and texts
of the two
lower court decisions, were presented in serial form over the
course of some
dozen of my quarterly issues. (See, e.g., our Vol. 21, No. 4,
table of
contents, below. All of our quarterly contents pages--back to
1967--can be
viewed at
http://webpages.metrolink.net/~cmueller/iii-f.html).
In understanding the Supreme Court's decision here--its
approval of
the cigarette industry's use of below-cost pricing to stop its
smallest
member, Liggett/ Brooke, from competing on price--it might
be helpful to
keep in mind a couple of general principles that heavily
influence the
decision process:
First, the Court decides cases in the context of the rulings
in each
case by the two lower courts, particularly that of the
appellate court it is
called upon to either affirm or reverse. It is always advisable,
then, to
read those 2 earlier opinions (along with, where possible, the
briefs on
appeal).
Second, the Supreme Court decides cases in the context
of its own
prior decisions on that same issue, particularly its most
recent ones. In
other words, the Court wants to develop a coherent body of
precedent, one
that yields the kind of rules it believes will best serve the
social and
economic ends favored by its sitting members. In the area of
monopolization
via predatory pricing, the Court's most recent pre-Brooke
decision was
Atlantic Richfield v. USA Petroleum (which is also one of my
'Dirty Dozen'
and can be viewed at http://webpages.metrolink.net/~
cmueller/dirty.html).
This opinion of the Court--which similarly approved predatory
pricing
against a small discounter--takes on added weight because
it was authored by
the late Justice Brennan, a noted "liberal" and a strong
supporter of
antitrust in his earlier years.
Third, each of the Justices has 3 or 4 "law clerks,"
generally
recent graduates of the more prestigious law schools, and
these youngsters
do the nuts-and-bolts writing of all those lengthy opinions,
replete with
voluminous footnotes aimed often at demonstrating their
learning (thanks to
the pro-monopoly brief, Areeda's textbook, Antitrust, a
summation of
Chicago-school economic theory) in the area at issue. The
Justices read the
briefs, listen to oral arguments, have a brief conference to
cast their
votes, one is assigned to write the opinion, and one or more of
his clerks
proceeds to draft an opinion that "justifies" the decision of the
majority
(5 votes). The Justices, focused on their role as makers of
national
policy, understandably don't vote on the footnotes.
Fourth, the country's highest Court doesn't agree to hear
cases in
order to resolve small points of no policy importance. It views
itself as a
policymaker, a shaper of important strands of national
policy. In the
antitrust field--where the basic, fundamental "rules of the
game" are laid
down for the whole of American industry--the Supreme Court
gets to set
"industrial policy" for America. Up to the 1970's, the Court
had accepted
the judgment of Congress that the wise policy was the
prevention of
"excessive concentration" of U.S. industry.
Beginning in roughly 1975, the Supreme Court decided
that Congress
had been wrong: "Consolidation" is a better policy. Today it
echoes Alan
Greenspan's judgment that Rockefeller's control of "80% of
the country's
refining capacity made considerable economic sense" and
that the antitrust
laws don't: "In summary, I find that the entire structure of
antitrust
statutes in this country is a jumble of economic irrationality
and
ignorance." (Alan Greenspan, Barron's, February 5, 1962, p.
8. Greenspan,
needless to relate, has never disavowed that firm opinion of
antitrust.)
The Liggett/Brookes decision should be read, then, with
this
question in mind: What POLICY message is the Court trying
to send? Its
audience, in antitrust cases, is composed largely of
corporate counsel for
the Fortune 500. It tells them what they, in turn, can tell their
giant
corporate clients. The policy message of this case--laissez
faire. If one
reads the 'Dirty Dozen,' that answer is even more
unmistakeable: Monopoly
is "economically" superior to competition, i.e., it's more
"efficient,"
yielding lower unit costs, larger output, and thus higher living
standards
for the American family.
As an example of how to read these 'Dirty Dozen'
antitrust decisions
of the U.S. Supreme Court, see my introduction (below) to the
first of this
group, the infamous Sylvania case of 1977.
Charles Mueller, Editor
ANTITRUST LAW & ECONOMICS REVIEW
http://webpages.metrolink.net/~cmueller
***********************
In Sylvania the Supreme Court, guided by an economist
at the
University of Maryland, decided that some kinds of
"competition" are more
deserving than others. In fact, said the Court, some forms of
competition
are positively harmful, because they are in conflict with the
better kind.
Specifically, the Court concluded that what is known as
"intrabrand"
competition--rivalry between retailers who sell a single
manufacturer's
branded goods (e.g., 2 Ford dealers in the same town)--is
harmful to the
consuming public. When competition breaks out within the
same "family" of
dealers, said the Court, it will inevitably degenerate into price
competition--which means the winner will be the most
aggressive "discounter"
who cuts to the bone on quality and service, while "free riding"
on the
brand's good name and on the advertising etc. of the loyal
dealers who don't
cut the price.
All this "intrabrand" price competition among a
manufacturer's
dealers will thus lower that manufacturer's quality/service to
the public,
says the Court, and ultimately cause a drop in its market
share, lessening
its viability as an "interbrand" competitor--as an effective rival
to the
manufacturers of competing brands of the same good. This
kind of rivalry
("interbrand"), holds the Court in Sylvania, is the truly
important kind of
economic competition and to nourish IT is the real and
abiding purpose of
the U.S. antitrust laws. Anything that hurts "interbrand"
competition
necessarily harms the consuming public; "intrabrand" (price)
competition
among dealers does this, so it is bad for the consumer.
Hence the ideal system, according to Sylvania, is one in
which each
manufacturer is given the maximum control over its
distributors and dealers,
protecting them from each other's competition. There is no
need to worry
about a rise in consumer prices, says the Court, because we
can depend upon
the competing MANUFACTURERS ("interbrand" competition)
to keep
consumer prices at the competitive level.
The Sylvania case of 1977, then, authorized U.S.
manufacturers to
eliminate competition at all levels of distribution, save their
own
(factory-level). Distribution (wholesaling and retailing), I need
not
remind this group, exceeds manufacturing in yearly dollar
volume.
Several hundred U.S. law professors are today busily
teaching their
students, even as we speak, that this decision is "good
economic science."
And our 1,000 U.S. judges are similarly occupied, this very
day, in killing
antitrust cases brought by dealers who have been cut off for
the evil
practice of "discounting"--selling below the price set by their
manufacturers--or for selling into the "territory" of a nearby
competitor.
Charles Mueller, Editor
ANTITRUST LAW & ECONOMICS REVIEW
http://webpages.metrolink.net/~cmueller
*****************************
Antitrust Law & Economics Review
Vol. 21, No. 4 (1989)
FOREWORD.....Editors.....1
Comment On Rose Acre Case.....Dr. William L. Baldwin,
Dr. Stephen A.
Rhoades, Dr. Ralph W. Anspach, Dr. Anthony J. Greco, Dr.
Pauline H.
Fox, Prof. Louis B. Schwartz.....13
Scherer-Ross 'Encyclopedia of Choice'.....Dr. William G.
Shepherd.....23
Shepherd Apology to Review.....Editors.....27
PREDATORY PRICING AND CONGRESSIONAL INTENT:
REJECTING
THE 'ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS' OF THE
AREEDA-TURNER AVC
RULE.....Judge Seybourn H. Lynne et al.....33
ENTRY, RECOUPMENT, AND HIGHER PRICES:
IRRELEVANCE OF
HIGH MARKET SHARES IN PREDATORY PRICING
(II).....Dr. John
Robert Umbeck.....47
PREDATORY PRICING WITH A 12% MARKET SHARE:
RECOUPMENT
VIA TACIT COLLUSION IN THE CIGARETTE
OLIOGOPOLY.....William
B. Burnett.....59
PREDATORY PRICING REQUIRES 60% MARKET
SHARE: NO
'OLIOGOPOLY' RECOUPMENT WITHOUT FIRM
'MARKET
POWER'.....Dr. Kenneth G. Elzinga.....85
DEFENDANT'S PROPOSED JURY INSTRUCTIONS:
PREDATION
REQUIRES AT LEAST 28% MARKET SHARE.....Martin
London et
al.....99
************************
Antitrust Law & Economics Review
Vol. 21, No. 3 (1989)
PREDATORY 'RECOUPMENT' CASES IN 3 U.S.
CIRCUITS: JURY
FINDINGS VERSUS JUDICIAL 'ECONOMIC'
THEORIZING.....Editors.....1
THE THRESHOLD OF MARKET POWER IN ECONOMICS:
4-FIRM
SHARE OF 40% TO 50%.....Dr. Willard F. Mueller.....11
COURT'S FINAL INSTRUCTIONS TO THE ROSE ACRE
JURY:
CRITERIA FOR COMPETITIVE INJURY.....Judge James E.
Noland.....23
ROSE ACRE'S LONG-TERM PREDATORY PRICE
DISCRIMINATION:
'PICKED OFF ONE AT A TIME'.....Warren S. Radler.....51
INNOVATION, LOWER COSTS, AND HARD PRICE
COMPETITION:
ROSE ACRE'S AMERICAN SUCCESS STORY.....Robert
P.
Johnstone.....63
THE ROSE ACRE DECISION AND BELOW-COST PRICE
DISCRIMINATION: SPOILED ECONOMIC EGGS IN THE
7TH
CIRCUIT (II).....Dr. Willard F. Mueller.....77
ENTRY, RECOUPMENT, AND HIGHER PRICES:
IRRELEVANCE OF
HIGH MARKET SHARES IN PREDATORY PRICING.....Dr.
John Robert
Umbeck.....89
************************